用户名: 密码: 验证码:
我国食品安全规制效果评价及规制体制重构研究
详细信息    本馆镜像全文|  推荐本文 |  |   获取CNKI官网全文
摘要
食品安全关乎民生,是保证人类生命健康和生活质量的基础。通过食品安全规制保证食品的质量安全不仅是一个技术问题,同时更是重要的经济、社会课题。随着农业生产能力、经济水平的不断提高,粮食安全以不再是大多数国家有关食品所关心的唯一问题,以食品质量安全程度为内涵的食品安全问题越来越得到政府决策者和社会公众的重视。近年来,我国食品安全事故频繁发生,食品安全问题甚至带来了严重的经济和社会后果,制约经济社会的可持续发展。加强食品安全规制,改善食品安全现状、控制食品安全事故发生成为消费者的迫切需求和政府关注的工作重点。十八届三中全会《决定》更明确指出,“完善统一权威的食品药品安全监管机构,建立最严格的覆盖全过程的监管制度,建立食品原产地可追溯制度和质量标识制度,保障食品药品安全。’
     食品安全问题主要来自于信息不对称的市场失灵。食品本身的经验品和信任品属性导致消费者在购买前无法获知其质量属性,甚至在购买后仍对食品的营养成分和安全程度等信息难以确定,而且几乎很多的食源性疾病为慢性疾病,即使食用后对健康产生负面影响,也无法将影响完全归因于消费了该食品。食品的信任品属性是食品买卖中存在信息不对称的根源。由于生产加工企业和销售者相对于消费者而言对于食品安全属性拥有绝对的信息优势,因而能够以次充好,通过销售假冒伪劣和不安全食品降低成本,同时威胁消费者的健康和生命安全。由此也说明了政府对食品安全问题进行干预,对企业行为进行监督规范,强制其揭示食品相关信息、通过质量安全认证体系,并对企业违法行为予以惩处的必要性。
     然而食品安全规制本身也存在各种问题,表现为政府失灵。学界的一个共识是,我国一直以来所形成的食品安全规制体制存在多部门共同规制、权责交叉重叠的“多头管理”问题。事实上,我国的食品安全规制体制一直处于不断发展和完善的过程当中,我国食品安全规制改革经历了以国家卫生部门为主导的食品安全规制体制向多部门分环节规制体制过渡,并在“大部制”改革的背景下逐渐形成卫生部门综合统筹的新规制体制的一系列过程,政府及相关部门对食品安全规制进行了多次重要、有益的改革。2013年3月份开始,在政府机构大部制改革的背景下,新组建食品药品监督管理总局整合了以往分散于卫生、农业、质检、工商、商务等各部门的食品安全规制职能和机构,使规制主体进一步集中,资源进一步整合。
     大部制改革伊始,改革成效将在未来较长的一段时间内逐步显现。由于食品市场存在的严重信息不对称问题未能得到有效解决,故而尽管政府不断加强食品安全规制力度,食品安全事故仍层出不穷。就目前而言,通过对我国食品安全规制效果评价发现规制中存在的不足和问题,从规制体制角度提出改善规制效果的路径,并论证食品安全规制领域大部制改革的正确性和进一步改革的方向,进而提出包括企业、消费者、社会组织在内的多元主体共同参与食品安全治理,以此作为一种制度补充和保障,仍具有重要的现实意义。
     因此本论文首先从我国食品安全规制体制改革过程入手,探究食品安全规制体制存在的问题,并对我国食品安全现状进行分析和评价。通过描述统计以及构建总体指标指出我国食品安全规制近年来呈现整体加强的趋势。
     在此之后,分别从企业和消费者角度对我国食品安全规制的效果进行评价。基于DEA(数据包络分析)的方法,从企业角度评价我国食品安全规制投入产出效率,发现以投入产出效率衡量的我国食品安全规制效果并不理想。进而以山东省为例,考察接受食品安全规制(HACCP)企业的经营情况、产品质量安全程度以及消费者满意度等规制效果指标。同样得出食品安全规制效果有待提升的结论。消费者角度的规制效果评价方面,以消费者营养健康状况受食品安全规制的影响作为食品安全规制的间接效果,运用中国营养健康调查数据(CHNS),运用倍差法(DID)结合倾向得分匹配法(PSM)分析食品安全规制对于消费者食品消费量、营养健康水平的影响。研究结果显示,尽管食品安全规制有助于恢复食品安全事故后消费者的信心,改善消费者营养和健康状况,但这种促进作用并不显著。
     实证分析的结果表明,我国目前的食品安全规制虽然在不断增强,但其效果并不明显。本文认为,导致这一现象的一个内在原因是,食品安全规制体制本身的复杂性,尤其是食品安全规制主体的权力配置问题。由于食品行业的规制本身面临多重委托—代理问题,存在着包括政府(规制机构)、企业、立法机构(代表消费者利益和社会福利)在内的多重委托代理关系,规制的环节中存在着道德风险,委托—代理链条冗长影响规制效率,同时作为这一委托—代理链条的中间环节的规制机构,是整个食品安全规制当中的关键,其权力配置的方式也直接影响着最终的规制效果。基于我国食品安全规制的体制特征,本文分别讨论了规制机构作为委托人和代理人的情况。规制机构作为代理人的情况下,通过构建多任务委托—代理模型,讨论食品安全规制体制进行大部制改革的必要性,发现走机构整合的“大部制”改革路线是我国食品安全规制体制改革的更优选择。而规制机构作为委托人的模型中,笔者则通过构建一个多委托人代理模型就可能存在规制俘获问题展开分析,提出进一步改革的方向。
     食品安全规制同时涉及政府规制机构、企业以及消费者在内的多方利益相关者,规制者行为并非决定规制效果的唯一因素。本文通过构建食品生产加工企业之间、企业与消费者之间、政府规制机构与企业之间的多个博弈模型,分析各利益相关主体的行为、最优策略选择以及其影响因素,发现加强政府监督控制力度、强化企业社会责任、充分发挥消费者和社会组织的监督作用的重要性。
     基于前文的分析,笔者提出将政府单一主体的食品安全规制扩展为多元主体共同主导的食品安全治理。指出在多元化的社会发展格局中,我国传统的以政府为单一治理主体的食品安全规制治理结构面临着诸多困境,已不能满足现代社会对食品安全治理的需求。最终提出通过构建规制者主导、企业自律、消费者参与、社会协同(包括行业协会、新闻媒体等)的食品安全合作治理框架,作为食品安全规制效果提升的最终制度保障。
Food safety which is related to people's livelihood is the foundation to guarantee the life, health and life quality of human being. It is not just a technical issue to ensure the quality and safety of food by food safety regulation, but even an important social and economic subject. With the improvement of agricultural production capacity and economic development level, food security is not the only concern of most countries any more, and the food safety problem which aims to elevate the level of food quality and safety is getting more attention from governmental decision makers and general public. In recent years, the food safety incidents have occurred frequently in China. The problem of food safety even causes severe economic and social consequence, and constraints the sustainable economic development. To strengthen the food safety regulation, change the current situation of food safety and control the accidents has been the urgent need of consumers and the key assignment of government. The Third Plenary Session of the eighteen cleared that "To improve food and drug safety regulatory agencies to be a unified authority, establishing the most stringent regulatory system to cover the whole process of food production and processing, establishing the traceability system of the origin food and quality labeling system to ensure food and drug safety.'
     The food safety problems arise from information asymmetry. The consumers can not acquire all the qualities of food because of the experience qualities and credence qualities of food before purchase, and even can't make sure the nutritional ingredient and safety level of food after buying. Besides, considering most foodborne diseases are chronic, the incurrence of disease can not be attributed to taking that food certainly. Accordingly, the credence qualities of food are the origin of informational asymmetry in the food trading. The food production and processing enterprises can sell seconds at best quality prices and reduce the cost by selling fake and unsafe commodities, because they have information advantages over consumers. And that actually endangers the health and life safety of consumers. This explains the necessity of governmental intervation on food safety issues, supervision for corporate behaviors, forcing the film to reveal information about food and pass the quality and safety certification system, and punishing the act in violation of regulations.
     However, there are also many defects even in food safety itself. We call that government failure. It has been an academic consensus that there are multi-sectional regulation and overlapping responsibilities problems so called "multiple management" in the food safety regulation system in our country. Actually, the food safety regulation system in China has been in continuous development and improvement process. The reform of food safety regulation system in China has been through the system led by state health department transitioned to multi-sectional regulation, and gradually formed the new system in the context of "large system" reform. The government and regulatory agencies has made a few important and beneficial reform of food safety regulation. From March2013, China Food and Drug Administration which is newly constructed integrated the functions and agencies that were decentralized among department of health, agriculture, quality supervision, industrial and commercial. That concentrates the regulation bodies, and integrates the resources.
     The reform of large system is still in the beginning, so the effectiveness will appear gradually in a long period of time. Although government has been strengthening food safety regulation continuously, the food safety incidents still emerged in an endless stream because the serious information asymmetry problem can not be fixed efficiently in food market. As far as it goes, it still has a profound significance to find deficiencies and problems in food safety regulation by effect evaluation, propose the path of improving the effect of regulation and demonstrate the validity of large system reform, then put forward food safety governance involves enterprises, consumers and social associations as an institutional supplement and insurance.
     Therefore, this thesis starts with the depiction and analysis of the course of food safety regulation reform in China to explore the problems existing in food safety regulation system, and then assesses the current situation of food safety in our country, shows the strengthening trend of food safety regulation during recent years by descriptive statistics and constructing an overall index.
     After that, we evaluate the effect of food safety regulation in China from enterprise and consumer perspective separately. By DEA method, we assess the input-output efficiency of food safety regulation from enterprise perspective, and find out that the effect of food safety regulation is not idealistic. And then we take Shandong for an example to investigate some regulatory effect index of enterprises that adopt HACCP including the state of operation, the degree of product quality, and consumers'satisfaction. We also come to a conclusion that the effect of food safety regulation needs to be further improved.
     From the consumers perspective, we empirically analyses the effect of food safety regulation on food consumption, the nutritional level and the health condition of consumers as the indirect effect of food safety regulation using difference in differences and propensity score matching method with CHNS database. The results show that:the consumer has restored the confidence on diary product. The food safety regulation has improved the growth of diary product consumption, and it also ameliorated the nutritional level and the health status of consumers. But in general, the promotion is not so significant and ideal.
     The empirical analysis shows that the effect of food safety regulation is not significant. This thesis suggests that one of the internal causes of this phenomenon is the complexity of food safety system, especially the distribution of power. The food industry confronts with multiple principal-agent problems. There are multi-level principal-agent relationships among government (regulatory agencies), enterprises, legislature and moral risk in the sessions of regulation. The principal-agent chain is so long to reduce the efficiency of regulation. The regulatory agency as the intermediate links of this principal-agent chain is the key of the whole food safety regulation. The mode of power allocation affects the final effect of regulation.
     Based on the characteristic of food safety regulation system in China, this paper analyses the situation of regulatory agencies as principal and agent respectively. When the regulatory agencies are considered as agent, this paper discusses the necessity of large system reform by constructing a multi-task principal-agent model, and points out that it it's a better choice to integrate the regulatory agencies. When the regulatory agencies are considered as principal, this paper analyses the probable regulatory capture, and proposes the direction of further reformation. Besides, we also consider the possibility of the cooperation of consumers and government.
     Food safety regulation involves many stakeholder including the government, enterprise and consumers. So the behavior of regulator is not the only issue that decides the effect of regulation. This thesis analyses the behavior, optimal strategy choice and the influencing factors of every stakeholder by constructing several game models. So we find out the importance of strengthening government supervision and control and corporate social responsibility. The consumers and social associations can play a role in food safety governance too.
     Based on the analysis above, this thesis recommends that it is a better choice to expand the conventional government-leading food safety regulation to food safety governance led by multiple subjects. In the pattern of pluralistic society, the conventional food safety governance structure is facing many difficulties, and can not meet the need of modern society. Eventually this paper makes a point to construct a food safety cooperative governance frame with regulator dominating, producer self-discipline, consumers involving and society cooperating, as the final institutional assurance to improve the effect of food safety regulation.
引文
[1]Hooker, N., J. Caswell. Regulatory targets and regimes for food safety:A comparison of North American and European Approaches [J].1996.
    [2]Lancaster, K.J. A New Approach to Consumer Theory [J]. The Journal of Political Economy,1966,74 (2),132-157.
    [3]Caswell, J. Using informational labeling to influence the market for quality in food products [J].1996.
    [4]Henson, S.,B. Traill. The demand for food safety:Market imperfections and the role of government [J]. Food Policy,1993,18 (2),152-162.
    [5]Sumner, J., G. Raven,R. Givney. Have changes to meat and poultry food safety regulation in Australia affected the prevalence of Salmonella or of salmonellosis? [J]. International journal of food microbiology,2004,92 (2),199-205.
    [6]Antle, J. M. Efficient food safety regulation in the food manufacturing sector [J]. American Journal of Agricultural Economics,1996,78 (5),1242-1247.
    [7]Unnevehr, L. J.,H. H. Jensen. HACCP as a regulatory innovation to improve food safety in the meat industry [J]. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 1996,78 (3),764-769.
    [8]Henson, S.,J. Caswell. Food safety regulation:an overview of contemporary issues [J]. Food Policy,1999,24 (6),589-603.
    [9]Segerson, K. Mandatory Versus Voluntary Approaches [J]. Agribusiness,1999, 15(1),53-70.
    [10]Starbird, S. A. Designing food safety regulations:The effect of inspection policy and penalties for noncompliance on food processor behavior [J]. Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics,2000,616-635.
    [11]Antle, J. M. Benefits and costs of food safety regulation [J]. Food Policy,1999, 24(6),19.
    [12]Antle, J. M. Economic analysis of food safety [J]. Handbook of agricultural economics,2001,11083-1136.
    [13]Valeeva, N. I., M. P. M. Meuwissen,R. B. M. Huirne. Economics of food safety in chains:a review of general principles [J]. NJAS-Wageningen Journal of Life Sciences,2004,51 (4),369-390.
    [14]Kuchler, F.,E. H. Golan. Assigning values to life:comparing methods for valuing health risks [R]. United States Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service,1999.
    [15]Ragona, M.,M. Mazzocchi. Food safety regulation, economic impact assessment and quantitative methods [J]. Innovation:The European Journal of Social Science Research,2008,21 (2),145-158.
    [16]Traill, W. B.,A. Koenig. Economic assessment of food safety standards:Costs and benefits of alternative approaches [J]. Food Control,2010,21 (12), 1611-1619.
    [17]Antle, J. M. No such thing as a free safe lunch:the cost of food safety regulation in the meat industry [J]. American Journal of Agricultural Economics,2000,82 (2),310-322.
    [18]Ollinger, M.,V. Mueller. Managing for safer food:The economics of sanitation and process controls in meat and poultry plants [R]. United States Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service,2003.
    [19]Ollinger, M.,D. L. Moore. The economic forces driving the costs of food safety regulation.2006 Annual meeting, July 23-26, Long Beach, CA, American Agricultural Economics Association (New Name 2008:Agricultural and Applied Economics Association).
    [20]Ollinger, M.,D. Moore. The Direct and Indirect Costs of Food-Safety Regulation [J]. Applied Economic Perspectives and Policy,2009,31 (2),247-265.
    [21]MacDonald, J. M.,S. Crutchfield. Modeling the costs of food safety regulation [J]. American Journal of Agricultural Economics,1996,78 (5),1285-1290.
    [22]Crutchfield, S. R., J. C. Buzby, T. Roberts, et al. Economic Assessment of Food Safety Regulations:The New Approach to Meat and Poultry Inspection [R]. United States Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service,1997.
    [23]Buzby, J. C., J. A. Fox, R. C. Ready, et al. Measuring consumer benefits of food safety risk reductions [J]. Journal of Agricultural and Applied Economics,1998, 3069-82.
    [24]Shogren, J. F., J. A. Fox, D. J. Hayes, et al. Observed choices for food safety in retail, survey, and auction markets [J]. American Journal of Agricultural Economics,1999,81 (5),1192-1199.
    [25]Caswell, J. A. Valuing food safety and nutrition [J].1995.
    [26]Latouche, K., P. Rainelli,D. Vermersch. Food safety issues and the BSE scare: some lessons from the French case [J]. Food Policy,1998,23 (5),347-356.
    [27]Roosen, J., J. L. Lusk,J. A. Fox. Consumer demand for and attitudes toward alternative beef labeling strategies in France, Germany, and the UK [J]. Agribusiness,2003,19 (1),77-90.
    [28]Holland, D.,C. R. Wessells. Predicting consumer preferences for fresh salmon: the influence of safety inspection and production method attributes [J]. Agricultural and Resource Economics Review,1998,27 1-14.
    [29]Halbrendt, C. K., J. D. Pesek Jr, A. Parsons, et al. Using conjoint analysis to assess consumers' acceptance of post-supplemented pork [J]. Valuing Food Safety and Nutrition,2000.
    [30]Fox, J. A., D. J. Hayes, J. F. Shogren, et al. Experimental methods in consumer preference studies [J]. Journal of food distribution research,1996,27 1-7.
    [31]Dickinson, D. L.,D. Bailey. Meat traceability:Are US consumers willing to pay for it? [J]. Journal of Agricultural and Resource Economics,2002,348-364.
    [32]Hammitt, J. K.,K. Haninger. Willingness to pay for food safety:sensitivity to duration and severity of illness [J]. American Journal of Agricultural Economics, 2007,89(5),1170-1175.
    [33]Teisl, M. F., N. E. Bockstael,A. Levy. Measuring the welfare effects of nutrition information [J]. American Journal of Agricultural Economics,2001,83 (1), 133-149.
    [34]Maldonado, E., S. Henson, J. Caswell,et al. Cost-benefit analysis of HACCP implementation in the Mexican meat industry [J]. Food Control,2005,16 (4), 375-381.
    [35]Unnevehr, L. J., M. I. G6mez,P. Garcia. The incidence of producer welfare losses from food safety regulation in the meat industry [J]. Review of agricultural economics,1998,20 (1),186-201.
    [36]Roosen, J.,D. A. Hennessy. Capturing experts' uncertainty in welfare analysis:An application to organophosphate use regulation in US apple production [J]. American Journal of Agricultural Economics,2001,83 (1),166-182.
    [37]Golan, E. H., S. J. Vogel, P. D. Frenzen, et al. Tracing the costs and benefits of improvements in food safety:the case of hazard analysis and critical control point program for meat and poultry [R]. United States Department of Agriculture, Economic Research Service,2000.
    [38]Mazzocchi, M., M. Ragona,A. Zanoli. A fuzzy multi-criteria approach for the ex-ante impact assessment of food safety policies [J]. Food Policy,2013,38. 177-189.
    [39]Henson, S. Estimating the incidence of food-borne Salmonella and the effectiveness of alternative control measures using the Delphi method [J]. International journal of food microbiology,1997,35 (3),195-204.
    [40]Loureiro, M. L. Liability and food safety provision:Empirical evidence from the US [J]. International Review of Law and Economics,2008,28 (3),204-211.
    [41]Holleran. E., M. E. Bredahl,L. Zaibet. Private incentives for adopting food safety and quality assurance [J]. Food Policy,1999,24 (6),669-683.
    [42]Law, M. T. The transaction cost origins of food and drug regulation. Annual conference of the international society for new institutional economics,2001.
    [43]Henson, S.,N. H. Hooker. Private sector management of food safety:public regulation and the role of private controls [J]. Management Review,2001,4 (7), 17.
    [44]Henson, S.,M. Heasman. Food safety regulation and the firm:understanding the compliance process [J]. Food Policy,1998,23 (1),9-23.
    [45]Yapp, C.,R. Fairman. Factors affecting food safety compliance within small and medium-sized enterprises:implications for regulatory and enforcement strategies [J]. Food Control,2006,17 (1),42-51.
    [46]Kong, D. Does corporate social responsibility matter in the food industry? Evidence from a nature experiment in China [J]. Food Policy,2012,37 (3), 323-334.
    [47]Wilcock, A., M. Pun, J. Khanona, et al. Consumer attitudes, knowledge and behaviour:a review of food safety issues [J]. Trends in Food Science & Technology,2004,15 (2),56-66.
    [48]Ogus, A. Rethinking self-regulation [J]. Oxford Journal of Legal Studies,1995, 15 (1),97-108.
    [49]Garcia Martinez, M., A. Fearne, J. A. Caswell, et al. Co-regulation as a possible model for food safety governance:Opportunities for public-private partnerships [J]. Food Policy,2007,32 (3),299-314.
    [50]Rouviere, E.,J. A. Caswell. From punishment to prevention:A French case study of the introduction of co-regulation in enforcing food safety [J]. Food Policy, 2012,37 (3),246-254.
    [51]Garcia Martinez, M., P. Verbruggen,A. Fearne. Risk-based approaches to food safety regulation:what role for co-regulation? [J]. Journal of Risk Research,2013, (ahead-of-print),1-21.
    [52]McCluskey, J. A game theoretic approach to organic foods:An analysis of asymmetric information and policy [J]. Agricultural and Resource Economics Review,2000,29(1),1-9.
    [53]Starbird, S. A. Moral hazard, inspection policy, and food safety [J]. American Journal of Agricultural Economics,2005,87 (1),15-27.
    [54]Mojduszka, E. M.,J. A. Caswell. A test of nutritional quality signaling in food markets prior to implementation of mandatory labeling [J]. American Journal of Agricultural Economics,2000,82 (2),298-309.
    [55]Rouviere, E. The implementation mechanisms of voluntary food safety systems [J]. Food Policy,2010,35 (5),412-418.
    [56]Tirole, J. The internal organization of government [J]. Oxford Economic Papers, 1994,1-29.
    [57]Dixit, A. Incentives and organizations in the public sector:An interpretative review [J]. Journal of human resources,2002,696-727.
    [58]Stone, R. Linear expenditure systems and demand analysis:an application to the pattern of British demand [J]. The Economic Journal,1954,64 (255),511-527.
    [59]Lluch, C.,R. Williams. Consumer demand systems and aggregate consumption in the USA:An application of the extended linear expenditure system [J]. Canadian Journal of Economics,1975,49-66.
    [60]Piggott, N. E., T. L. Marsh. Does Food Safety Information Impact U.S. Meat Demand? [J]. American Journal of Agricultural Economics,2004,86(1).
    [61]Morgan, O. A., J. C. Whitehead, W. L. Huth, et al. A Split-Sample Revealed and Stated Preference Demand Model to Examine Homogenous Subgroup Consumer Behavior Responses to Information and Food Safety Technology Treatments [J]. Environmental and Resource Economics,2012,10.
    [62]Adrain, J., R. Daniel. Impact of Socioeconomic Factors on Consumption of Selected Food Nutrients in the United States [J]. American Journal of Agricultural Economics,1976,58(1).
    [63]Jin, G. Z., P. Leslie. The Effect of Information on Product Quality:Evidence from Restaurant Hygiene Grade Cards [J]. Quarterly Journal of Economics,2003, 118(2).
    [64]Shimshack, J. P., M. B. Ward. Mercury Advisories and Household Health Trade-off [J]. Journal of Health Economics,2010,29(5).
    [65]Robert, M, Kaplan R M, Anderson J P. A General Health Policy Model:Update and Applications[J], HSR:Health Services Research,1988,23(2),203-235.
    [66]Grossman, M, On the Concept of Health Capital and the Demand for Health[J]. Journal of Political Economy,1972,80(2) 223-255.
    [67]Rosenbaum, P R, Rubin D B. The central role of the propensity score in observational studies for causal effects [J]. Econometrica,1983,70(1),41-55.
    [68]Heckman, J J, Robb R. Alternative Models for Evaluating the Impact of Interventions. Longitudinal Analysis of Labor Market Data [M]. Cambridge University Press,1985.
    [69]Blundel, R, Costa M. Evaluation Methods for Non-Experimental Data [J]. Fiscal Studies,2000,21(4),427-468.
    [70]Heyman, F, Sjoholm F, Tingvall P G. Is there really a foreign ownership wage premium? Evidence from matched employer-employee data [J]. Journal of International Economics,2007,73(2),355-376.
    [71]Bockerman, P, Ilmakunnas P. Unemployment and self-assessed health:Evidence from panel data[J]. Health Economics,2009,18(2),161-179.
    [72]Heckman, J, Ichimura H, Todd P. Matching as an econometric evaluation estimator:evidence from evaluating a job training programme [J]. Review of Economic Studies,1997,64(4),605-654.
    [73]Heckman, J, Ichimura H, Smith J, et al. Characterizing selection bias using experimental data [J]. Econometrica,1998,66 (5),1017-1098.
    [74]Darby, M. R.,E. Karni. Free competition and the optimal amount of fraud [J]. Journal of law and economics,1973,16 (1),67-88.
    [75]Nelson, P. Information and consumer behavior [J]. The journal of political economy,1970,78 (2),311-329.
    [76]Holmstrom, B.,P. Milgrom. Multitask principal-agent analyses:Incentive contracts, asset ownership, and job design [J]. JL Econ. & Org.,1991,724-52.
    [77]Itoh, H. Cooperation in hierarchical organizations:An incentive perspective [J]. JL Econ. & Org.,1992,8321-345.
    [78]Itoh. H. Job design, delegation and cooperation:A principal-agent analysis [J]. European Economic Review,1994,38 (3),691-700.
    [79]Itoh, H. Job design and incentives in hierarchies with team production [R]. Institute of Social and Economic Research, Osaka University,1996.
    [80]Meyer, M. A., T. E. Olsen,G. Torsvik. Limited intertemporal commitment and job design [J]. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization,1996,31 (3), 401-417.
    [81]Laffont, J.-J., J. Tirole. A theory of incentives in procurement and regulation [M], Cambridge:MIT Press.
    [82]Martimort, D. The multiprincipal nature of government [J]. European Economic Review,1996,40 (3),673-685.
    [83]Laffont, J.-J.,D. Martimort. Transaction costs, institutional design and the separation of powers [J]. European Economic Review,1998,42 (3),673-684.
    [84]Laffont, J.-J.,D. Martimort. Separation of regulators against collusive behavior [J]. The Rand journal of economics,1999,232-262.
    [85]Laffont, J.-J.,M. Meleu. Separation of powers and development [J]. Journal of Development Economics,2001,64 (1),129-145.
    [86]Laffont, J.-J.,J. Pouyet. The subsidiarity bias in regulation [J]. Journal of Public Economics,2004,88 (1),255-283.
    [87]Laffont, J.-J., Zantman, Information acquisition, political game and the delegation of authority [J]. European Journal of Political Economy,2002,18,407-428.
    [88]Calzolari, G., A. Pavon. On the optimality of privacy in sequential contracting [J]. Journal of Economic Theory 2006,130,168-204.
    [89]Kreps, D., R. Wilson. Reputation and imperfect information [J]. Journal of Economic Theory,1982,27,263-279.
    [90]刘畅,张浩,安玉发.中国食品质量安全薄弱环节,本质原因及关键控制点研 究——基于1460个食品质量安全事件的实证分析[J].农业经济问题,2011,(1),24-31.
    [91]徐立清,孟菲.中国食品安全研究报告(2011)[M].科学出版社,2012.
    [92](美)史普博.管制与市场[M].格致出版社,上海三联书店,上海人民出版社,2008.
    [93]张红凤.西方规制经济学的变迁[M].经济科学出版社,2005.
    [94]周德翼,杨海娟.食物质量安全管理中的信息不对称与政府监管机制[J].中国农村经济,2002,(6),29-35.
    [95]廖卫东,肖可生,时洪洋.论我国食品公共安全规制的制度建设[J].当代财经,2009,(11),93-98.
    [96]李怀,赵万里.中国食品安全规制制度的变迁与设计[J].财经问题研究,2009,(10),16-23.
    [97]王耀忠.食品安全监管的横向和纵向配置——食品安全监管的国际比较与启示[J].中国工业经济,2005,12(12),64-65.
    [98]赵学刚.统一食品安全监管:国际比较与我国的选择[J].中国行政管理,2009,(3),103-107.
    [99]李先国.发达国家食品安全监管体系及其启示[J].财贸经济,2011,(7).
    [100]颜海娜.食品安全监管部门间关系研究——交易费用理论的视角[M].中国社会科学出版社,2010.
    [101]冀玮.多部门食品安全监管的必要性分析[J].中国行政管理,2012,(2),54-58.
    [102]刘为军,魏益民,潘家荣等.现阶段中国食品安全控制绩效的关键影响因素分析——基于9省(市)食品安全示范区的实证研究[J].商业研究,2008,(7).
    [103]胡颖廉.食品安全监管的框架分析与细节观察[J].改革,201 1,(10),147-154.
    [104]刘鹏.中国食品安全监管——基于体制变迁与绩效评估的实证研究[J].公共管理学报,2010,(2),63-78.
    [105]王能,任运河.食品安全监管效率评估研究[J].财经问题研究,2011,(12).
    [106]白丽,马成林.巩顺龙.中国食品企业实施HACCP食品安全管理体系的实证研究[J].食品工业科技,2005,(9),16-18.
    [107]王志刚,翁燕珍,杨志刚等.食品加工企业采纳HACCP体系认证的有效性:来自全国482家食品企业的调研[J].中国软科学,2006,(9),69-75.
    [108]刘霞,郑风田,罗红旗.企业遵从食品安全规制的成本研究——基于北京市食品企业采纳HACCP的实证分析[J].经济体制改革,2008,(6),73-78.
    [109]周洁红.农户蔬菜质量安全控制行为及其影响因素分析[J].中国农村经济,2006,(11),25-33.
    [110]周洁红,胡剑锋.蔬菜加工企业质量安全管理行为及其影响因素分析——以浙江为例[J].中国农村经济,2009,(3),45-56.
    [111]孙世民,李娟,张健如.优质猪肉供应链中养猪场户的质量安全认知与行为分析——基于9省份653家养猪场户的问卷调查[J].农业经济问题,2011,(3),76-81.
    [112]韩杨,陈建先,李成贵.中国食品追溯体系纵向协作形式及影响因素分析—以蔬菜加工企业为例[J].中国农村经济,2011,(12),54-67.
    [113]叶俊焘,猪肉加工企业质量安全追溯系统后向控制绩效研究[J].农业经济问题,2012,(8),84-91.
    [114]冯忠泽,李庆江.消费者农产品质量安全认知及影响因素分析冰[J].中国农村经济,2008,(1),23-29.
    [115]王锋,张小栓,穆维松等.消费者对可追溯农产品的认知和支付意愿分析[J].中国农村经济,2009,(3),68-74.
    [116]何坪华,凌远云,周德翼.食品价值链及其对食品企业质量安全信用行为的影响[J].农业经济问题,2009,(1),48-52.
    [117]王秀清,孙云峰.我国食品市场上的质量信号问题[J].中国农村经济,2002,(5).
    [118]李想.信任品质量的一个信号显示模型:以食品安全为例[J].世界经济 文汇,2011,(1).
    [119]张璐,周晓唯.逆向选择与道德风险条件下的最优激励契约模型研究——关于食品行业的监管问题[J].制度经济学研究,2012,(1).
    [120]徐晓新.中国食品安全:问题,成因,对策[J].农业经济问题,2002,(10),45-48.
    [121]张红凤,陈小军.我国食品安全问题的政府规制困境与治理模式重构[J].理论学刊,2011,(7),63-67.
    [122]陈刚,张浒.食品安全中政府监管职能及其整体性治理——基于整体政府理论视角[J].云南财经大学学报,2012,(5),152-160.
    [123]吴元元.信息基础,声誉机制与执法优化——食品安全治理的新视野[J].中国社会科学,2012,(6),115-133.
    [124]汪鸿昌,肖静华,谢康等.食品安全治理——基于信息技术与制度安排相结合的研究[J].中国工业经济,2013,(3).
    [125]2010年中国食品工业年鉴[M].中国食品工业协会,2012.
    [126]2000年中国卫生年鉴[M].人民卫生出版社,2000.
    [127]2001年中国卫生年鉴[M].人民卫生出版社,2001.
    [128]2008年中国食品药品监督管理年鉴[M].中国华侨出版社,2008.
    [129]201 0年中国食品药品监督管理年鉴[M].国家食品药品监督管理局,2011.
    [130]2011年中国食品药品监督管理年鉴[M].国家食品药品监督管理局,2012.
    [131]1999年中国卫生统计提要[EB].中华人民共和国国家卫生和计划生育委员会网站,http://www.moh.gov.cn/wsb/pzcjd/200804/24131.shtml.
    [132]2000年中国卫生统计提要[EB].中华人民共和国国家卫生和计划生育委员会网站,http://www.moh.gov.cn/zwgkzt/ptjty/200805/35308.shtml.
    [133]2001年中国卫生统计提要[EB].中华人民共和国国家卫生和计划生育委员会网站,http://www.moh.gov.cn/zwgkzt/ptjty/200805/35309.shtml.
    [134]2003年中国卫生统计提要[EB].中华人民共和国国家卫生和计划生育 委员会网站,http://www.moh.gov.cn/zwgkzt/ptjty/200805/35310.shtml.
    [135]中华人民共和国卫生部.2004年中国卫生统计年鉴[M].中国协和医科大学出版社,2004.
    [136]中华人民共和国卫生部.2005年中国卫生统计年鉴[M].中国协和医科大学出版社,2005.
    [137]中华人民共和国卫生部.2006年中国卫生统计年鉴[M].中国协和医科大学出版社,2006.
    [138]中华人民共和国卫生部.2007年中国卫生统计年鉴[M].中国协和医科大学出版社,2007.
    [139]中华人民共和国卫生部.2008年中国卫生统计年鉴[M].中国协和医科大学出版社,2008.
    [140]中华人民共和国卫生部.2009年中国卫生统计年鉴[M].中国协和医科大学出版社,2009.
    [141]中华人民共和国卫生部.2010年中国卫生统计年鉴[M].中国协和医科大学出版社,2010.
    [142]中华人民共和国卫生部.2011年中国卫生统计年鉴[M].中国协和医科大学出版社,2011.
    [143]2010年我国卫生事业发展统计公报[EB].中国疾病预防控制中心网站,http://www.chinacdc.cn/tjsj/gjwstjsj/201105/t20110504_43268.htm.
    [144]国家食品药品监督管理总局网站,http://www.sda.gov.cn/WS01/CL0001/.
    [145]国家质量监督检验检疫总局网站,http://www.aqsiq.gov.cn/.
    [146]程立超.食品消费的代际差异——基于中国健康与营养调查的实证研究[J].南方经济,2009,(7),26-35.
    [147]赵忠,侯振刚.我国城镇居民的健康需求与Grossman模型——来自截面数据的证据[J].经济研究,2005,(10),79-90.
    [148]周黎安,陈烨.中国农村税费改革的政策效果:基于双重差分模型的估计[J].经济研究,2005,(8)44-53.
    [149]马双,臧文斌,甘犁.新型农村合作医疗保险对农村居民食物消费的影响分 析[J].经济学(季刊),2010,10(1),249-270.
    [150]李湘君,王中华,林振平.新型农村合作医疗对农民就医行为及健康的影响——基于不同收入层次的分析[J].世界经济文汇,2012,(3),58-75.
    [151]皮建才.中国大部制改革的组织经济学考察[J].中国工业经济,2011,(5),90-98.
    [152]张维迎.法律制度的信息基础[J].经济研究,2002,(2),4-13.

© 2004-2018 中国地质图书馆版权所有 京ICP备05064691号 京公网安备11010802017129号

地址:北京市海淀区学院路29号 邮编:100083

电话:办公室:(+86 10)66554848;文献借阅、咨询服务、科技查新:66554700